The World Is Flat
Thomas Friedman
Farrar, Straus & Giroux, New York (USA), first edition, 2005 (2005)
488 pages, including index.
|
There is nothing here yet but a collection of quotes from the book that I will
be expanding when I find the time.
If you put The Lexus and the Olive Tree and this book together, the broad historical argument you end
up with is that there have been three great eras of globalization. The
first lasted from 1492 —when Columbus set sail, opening trade between the
Old World and the New World— until around 1800. I would call this era
Globalization 1.0. It shrank the world from a size large to a size medium.
Globalization 1.0 was about countries and muscles. That is, in
Globalization 1.0 the key agent of change, the dynamic force driving the
process of global integration was how much brawn —how much muscle, how
much horsepower, wind power, or, later, steam power— your country had
and how creatively you could deploy it. In this era, countries and governments
(often inspired by religion or imperialism or a combination of both) led the
way in breaking down walls and knitting the world together, driving global
integration. In Globalization 1.0, the primary questions were: Where does my
country fit into global competition and opportunities? How can I go global and
collaborate with others through my country?
The second great era, Globalization 2.0, laste roughly from 1800 to 2000,
interrupted by the Great Depression and World Wars I and II. This era shrank
the world from a size medium to a size small. In Globalization 2.0, the key
agent of change, the dynamic force driving global integration, was
multinational companies. These multinationals went global for markets
and labor, spearheaded first by the expansion of the Dutch and English
joint-stock companies and the Industrial Revolution. In the first half of
this era, global integration was powered by falling transportation costs,
thanks to the steam engine and the railroad, and in the second half by falling
telecommunications costs —thanks to the diffusion of the telegraph,
telephones, the PC, satellites, fiber-optic cable, and the early version of
the World Wide Web. It was during this era that we really saw the birth and
maturation of a global economy, in the sense that there was enough movement
of goods and information from continent to continent for there to be a global
market, with a global arbitrage in products and labor. The dynamic forces
behind this era of globalization were breakthroughs in hardware —from
steamships and railroads in the beginning to telephones and mainframe
computers toward the end. And the big questions in this era were: Where does
my company fit into the global economy? How does it take advantage of the
opportunities? How can I go global and collaborate with others through my
company? The Lexus and the Olive Tree was primarily about the climax
of this era, an era when the walls started falling all around the world, and
integration, and the backlash to it, went to a whole new level. But even as
the falls fell, there were still a lot of barriers to seamless global
integration. Remember, when Bill Clinton was elected president in 1992,
virtually no one outside of government and academy had e-mail, and when I was
writing The Lexus and the Olive Tree in 1998, the Internet and
e-commerce were just taking off.
Well, they took off —along with a lot of other things that came together
while I was sleeping. And that is why I argue in this book that around the
year 2000 we entered a whole new era: Globalization 3.0. Globalization 3.0 is
shrinking the world from a size small to a size tiny and flattening the playing
field at the same time. And while the dynamic force in Globalization 1.0 was
countries globalizing and the dynamic force in Globalization 2.0 was companies
globalizing, the dynamic force in Globalization 3.0 —the thing that
gives it its unique character— is the newfound power for
individuals to collaborate and compete globally. And the lever that is
enabling individuals and groups to go global so easily and so seamlessly is not
horsepower, and not hardware, but software —all sorts of new
applications— in conjunction with the creation of a global fiber-optic
network that has made us all next-door neighbors. Individuals must,
and can, now ask, Where do I fit into the global competition and
opportunities of the day, and how can I, on my own, collaborate with
others globally?
(pp. 9-10)
I had never seen what a supply chain looked like in action until I visited
Wal-Mart headquarters in
Bentonville, Arkansas. My Wal-Mart hosts took me
over to the 1.2-million-square-foot distribution center, where we climbed up
to a viewing perch and watched the show. On one side of the building, scores
of white Wal-Mart trailer trucks were dropping off boxes of merchandise from
thousands of different suppliers. Boxes large and small were fed up a
conveyor belt at each loading dock. These little conveyor belts fed into
a bigger belt, like streams feeding into a powerful river. Twenty-four
hours a day, seven days a week, the suppliers' trucks feed the twelve miles
of conveyor streams, and the conveyor streams feed into a huge Wal-Mart river
of boxed products. But that is just half the show. As the Wal-Mart river
flows along, an electric eye reads the bar codes on each box on its way to the
other side of the building. There, the river parts again into a hundred
streams. Electric arms from each stream reach out and guide the boxes
—ordered by particular Wal-Mart stores— off the main river and
down its stream, where another conveyor belt sweeps them into a waiting
Wal-Mart truck, which will rush these particular products onto the shelves of
a particular Wal-Mart store somewhere in the country. There, a consumer
will lift one of these products off the shelf, and the cashier will scan it in,
and the moment that happens, a signal will be generated. That signal will go
out across the Wal-Mart network to the supplier of that product —whether
that supplier's factory is in coastal China or coastal Maine. That signal
will pop up on the supplier's computer screen and prompt him to make another
of that item and ship it via the Wal-Mart supply chain, and the whole cycle
will start anew. So no sooner does your arm lift a product off the local
Wal-Mart's shelf and onto the checkout counter than another mechanical arm
starts making another one somewhere in the world. Call it "the Wal-Mart
Symphony" in multiple movements —with no finale. It just plays over
and over 24/7/365: delivery, sorting, packing, distribution, buying,
manufacturing, reordering, delivery, sorting, packing...
(p. 128)
As consumers, we love supply chains, because they deliver us all sorts of
goods —from tennis shoes to laptop computers— at lower and lower
prices. That is how Wal-Mart became the world's biggest retailer. But as
workers, we are sometimes ambivalent or hostile to these supply chains,
because they expose us to higher and higher pressures to compete, cut costs,
and also, at times, cut wages and benefits. This is how Wal-Mart became
one of the world's most controversial companies. No company has been more
efficient at improving its supply chain (and thereby flattening the world)
than Wal-Mart; and no company epitomizes the tension that supply chains
evoke between the consumer in us and the worker in us than Wal-Mart.
(p. 129)
It is my contention that the opening of the Berlin Wall, Netscape, work flow, outsourcing, offshoring,
open-sourcing, insourcing, supply-chaining, in-forming, and the steroids amplifying them all reinforced
one another, like complementary goods. They just needed time to converge and
start to work together in a complementary, mutually enhancing fashion. That
tipping point arrived sometime around the year 2000.
The net result of this convergence was the creation of a global,
Web-enabled playing field that allows for multiple forms of collaboration
—the sharing of knowledge and work— in real time, without regard
to geography, distance, or, in the near future, even language. No, not
everyone has access yet to this platform, this playing field, but it is
open today to more people in more places on more days in more ways than
anything like it ever before in the history of the world. This is what I
mean when I say the world has been flattened [the author's underline]. It
is the complementary convergence of the ten flatteners creating this new global
playing field for multiple forms of collaboration.
(pp. 176-177)
I first began thinking about the great sorting out after a conversation
with Harvard
University's noted political theorist Michael J. Sandel. Sandel startled me slightly by
remarking that the sort of flattening process that I was describing was
actually first identified by Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels in the Communist Manifesto, published in 1848. While the shrinking
and flattening of the world that we are seeing today constitute a difference
of degree from what Marx saw happening in his day, said Sandel, it is
nevertheless part of the same historical trend Marx highlighted in his
writings on capitalism
—the inexorable march of technology and capital to remove all barriers,
boundaries, frictions, and restraints to global commerce.
"Marx was one of the first to glimpse the possibility of the world as a global
market, uncomplicated by national boundaries", Sandel explained. "Marx was
capitalism's fiercest critic, and yet he stood in awe of its power to break
down barriers and create a worldwide system of production and consumption.
In the Communist Manifesto, he described capitalism as a force that
would dissolve all feudal, national, and religious identities, giving rise to
a universal civilization governed by market imperatives. Marx considered it
inevitable that capital would have its way —inevitable and also
desirable. Because once capitalism destroyed all national and religious
allegiances, Marx thought, it would lay bare the stark struggle between
capital and labor. Forced to compete in a global race to the bottom, the
workers of the world would unite in a global revolution to end oppression.
Deprived of consoling distractions such as patriotism and religion, they
would see their exploitation clearly and rise up to end it".
(pp. 201-202)
Friedman goes on to quote Marx at length:
All fixed, fast, frozen relations, with their train of ancient and venerable
prejudices and opinions, are swept away, all new-formed ones become
antiquated before they can ossify. All that is solid melts into the air,
all that is holy is profaned, and man is at last compelled to face with sober
senses his real conditions of life and his relations with his kind. The
need of a constantly expanding market for its products chases the bourgeoisie
over the whole surface of the globe. It must nestle everywhere, settle
everywhere, establish connections everywhere. The bourgeoisie has through
its exploitation of the world market given a cosmopolitan character to
production and consumption in every country. To the great chagrin of
reactionaries, it has drawn from under the feet of industry the natioanl
ground on which it stood. All old-established national industries have been
destroyed or are daily being destroyed. They are dislodged by new industries,
whose introduction becomes a life and death question for all civilised nations,
by industries that no longer work up indigenous raw material, but raw material
drawn from the remotest zones; industries whose products are consumed, not
only at home, but in every quarter of the globe. In place of the old wants,
satisfied by the production of the country, we find new wants, requiring for
their satisfaction the products of distant lands and climes. In place of
the old local and national seclusion and self-sufficiency, we have
intercourse in every direction, universal inter-dependence of nations. And
as in material, also in intellectual production. The intellectual creations
of individual nations become common property. National one-sidedness
and narrow-mindedness become more and more impossible, and from the
numerous national and local literatures there arises a world literature.
The bourgeoisie, by the rapid improvement of all instruments of production,
by the immensely facilitated means of communication, draws all, even the most
barbarian nations into civilisation. The cheap prices of commodities are
the heavey artillery with which it batters down all Chinese walls, with which
it forces the barbarians' intensely obstinate hatred of foreigners to
capitulate. It compels all nations, on pain of extinction, to adopt the
bourgeois mode of production; it compels them to introduce what it calls
civilisation into their midst, i.e., to become bourgeois themselves. In one
word, it creates a world after its own image.
(pp. 202-203)
So, what are the conclusions Friedman extracts from all this?
It is hard to believe that Marx published that in 1848. Referring to the
Communist Manifesto, Sandel told me, you are arguing something
similar. What you are arguing is that developments in information
technology are enabling companies to squeeze out all the inefficiencies and
friction from their markets and business operations. That is what your
notion of "flattening" really means. But a flat, frictionless world is a
mixed blessing. It may, as you suggest, be good for global business. Or it
may, as Marx believed, augur well for a proletarian revolution. But it may
also pose a threat to the distinctive places and communities that give us
our bearings, that locate us in the world. From the first stirrings of
capitalism, people have imagined the possibility of the world as a perfect
market —unimpeded by protectionist pressures, disparate legal systems,
cultural and linguistic differences, or ideological disagreement. But this
vision has always bumped up against the world as it actually is —full
of sources of friction and inefficiency. Some obstacles to a frictionless
global market are truly sources of waste and lost opportunities. But some
of these inefficiencies are institutions, habits, cultures, and traditions
that people cherish precisely because they reflect nonmarket values like
social cohesion, religious faith, and national pride. If global markets and
new communications flatten those differences, we may lose something
important. That is why the debate about capitalism has been, from the
very beginning, about which frictions, barriers, and boundaries are mere
source of waste and inefficiency, and which are sources of identity and
belonging that we should try to protect. From the telegraph to the
Internet, every new communications tehcnology has promised to shrink the
distance between people, to increase access to information, and to bring us
ever closer to the dream of a perfectly efficient, frictionless global
market. And each time, the question for society arises with renewed
urgency: To what extent should we stand aside, "get with the program", and
do all we can to squeeze out yet more inefficiencies, and to what extent
should we lean against the current for the sake of values that global markets
can't supply? Some sources of friction are worth protecting, even in the
face of a global economy that threatens to flatten them".
(pp. 203-204)
Now, the irony is that this conversation with Michael J. Sandel can pretty
much sum up Friedman's whole book. Or, in different words, other than the
massive marketing operation that managed to sell this book all over the world
as a great and refreshingly new point of view and, of course, Friedman's well
known ability to put things in a prose that is at the same time easy to read,
entertaining and clarifying, what he has to say in The World Is Flat
was already said by Marx more than 150 years ago.
Given these conflicting emotions and pressures, there is potential here
for American politics to get completely reshuffled —with workers and
corporate interests realigning themselves into different parties. Think
about it: Social conservatives from the right wing of the Republican party,
who do not like globalization or closer integration with the world because it
brings too many foreigners and foreign cultural mores into America, might
align themselves with unions from the left wing of the Democratic Party, who
don't like globalization for the way it facilitates the outsourcing and
offshoring of jobs. They might be called the Wall Party and militate for
more friction and far everywhere. Let's face it: Republican cultural
conservatives have much more in common with the steelworkers of Youngstown,
Ohio, the farmers of rural China, and the mullahs of central Saudi Arabia,
who would also like more walls, than they do with investment bankers on Wall
Street or service workers linked to the global economy in Palo Alto, who
have been enriched by the flattening of the world.
(p. 221)
My mind just kept telling me: "Ricardo is right, Ricardo is right, Ricardo is
right". David Ricardo (1772-1823) was the English economist who developed the free-trade theory of comparative advantage, which stipulates
that if each nation specializes in the production of goods in which it has a
compartive cost advantage then trades with other nations for the goods in
which they specialize, there will be an overall gain in trade, and overall
income levels should rise in each trading country. So if all these
Indian techies were doing what was their comparative advantage and then
turning around and using their income to buy all the products from America
that are our comparative advantage —from Corning Glass to Microsoft
Windows— both our countries would benefit, even if some individual
Indians and Americans might have to shift jobs in the transition. And one
can see evidence of this mutual benefit in the sharp increase in exports and
imports between the United States and India in recent years.
(...)
Let me illustrate this with an example. Imagine that there are only two
countries in the world —America and China. And imagine that the American
economy has only 100 people. Of those 100 people, 80 are well-educated knowledge workers and
20 are less-educated low-skilled workers. Now imagine that the world goes flat
and America enters into a free-trade agreement with China, which has 1,000
people but is a less developed country. So today China too has only 80
well-educated knowledge workers out of 1,000, and it has 920 low-skilled
workers. Before America entered into its free-trade agreement with China,
there were only 80 knowledge workers in its world. Now there 160 in our
two-country world. The American knowledge workers feel like they have more
competition, and they do. But if you look at the prize they are going after,
it is now a much expanded and more complex market. It went from a market of
100 people to a market of 1,100 people, with many more needs and wants. So it
should be win-win for both the American and the Chinese knowledge workers.
(pp. 225-229)
And always remember: The Indians and Chinese are not racing us to the
bottom. They are racing us to the top —and that is a good thing!
They want higher standards of living, not sweatshops; they want brand names,
not junk; they want to trade their motor scooters for cars and their pens and
pencils for computers. And the more they do that, the higher they climb, the
more room is created at the top —because the more they have, the more
they spend, the more diverse product markets become, and the more niches for
specialization are created as well.
(p. 233)
Lucky for us, we were the only economy standing after World War II, and we
had no serious competition for forty years. That gave us a huge head of
steam but also a huge sense of entitlement and complacency —not to
mention a certain tendency in recent years to extol consumption over hard work,
investment, and long-term thinking. When we got hit with 9/11, it was a
once-in-a-generation opportunity to summon the nation to sacrifice, to address
some of its pressing fiscal, energy, science, and education shortfalls
—all the things that we had let slide. But our president did not
summon us to sacrifice. He summoned us to go shopping.
(p. 252)
In the winter of 2004 I had tea in Tokyo with Richard C. Koo, chief economist
for the Nomura Research Institute.
I tested out on Richard my "coefficient of flatness": the notion that the
flatter one's country is —that is, the fewer natural resources it
has— the better off it will be in a flat world. The ideal country
in a flat world is the one with no natural resources, because
countries with no natural resources tend to dig inside themselves. They
try to tap the energy, entrepeneurship, creativity, and intelligence of
their own people —men and women— rather than drill an oil well.
Taiwan is a barren rock in
a typhoon-laden sea, with virtually no natural resources —nothing but
the energy, ambition, and talent of its own people— and today it has
the third-largest financial reserves in the world. The success of Honk Kong, Japan, South Korea, and coastal China can all be traced to a similar flatness.
(pp. 262-263)
While many of the old corporate and government safety nets will vanish under
global competition in the flat world, some fat still needs to be maintained,
and even added. As everyone who worries about his or her health knows, there
is "good fat" and "bad fat" —but everybody needs some fat. That is also
true of every country in the flat world. Social Security is good fat. We
need to keep it. A welfare system that discourages people from working is
bad fat. The sort of good fat that actually needs to be added for a flat
world is wage
insurance.
(...)
The idea of wage insurance was first proposed in 1986 by Harvard's Robert
Lawrence and Robert E. Litan of the Brookings Institution, in a book called Saving Free Trade. The idea languished for a while until it started
to catch fire again with an updated analysis by Kletzer and Litan in 2001. It
got further political clout from the bipartisan US Trade Deficit Commission in 2001. This commission
couldn't agree on anything —including the causes of or what to do about
the trade deficit— other than the wisdom of wage insurance.
"Trade creates winners and losers, and what we were thinking about were
mechanisms by which the winners could compensate the losers, and particularly
losers who were enjoying high wages in a particular job and suddenly found
their new employment at much lower wages", said Lawrence. The way to think
about this, he explained, is that every worker has "general skills and
specific skills" for which they are paid, and when you switch jobs you
quickly discover which is which. So you might have a college and CPA degree,
or you might have a high school degree and the ability to operate a lathe.
Both skills were reflected in your wages. But suppose one day your lathe job
gets moved to China or your basic accounting work is outsourced to India and
you have to go out and find a new job. Your new employer will not likely
compensate you much for your specific skills, because your knowledge as a
machine tool operator or a general accountant is probably of less use to him
or her. You will be paid largely for your general skills, your high school
education or college degree. Wage insurance would compensate you for your
old specific skills, for a ser period of time, while you take a new job and
learn new specific skills.
The standard state-run unemployment insurance program eases some of the pain
for workers, but it does not address thei bigger concerns of declining wages
in a new job and the inability to pay for health insurance while they are
unemployed and searching. To qualify for wage insurance, workers seeking
compensation for job loss would have to meet three criteria. First, they
would have to have lost their job through some form of displacement
—offshoring, outsourcing, downsizing, or factory closure. Second, they
would have to have held the job for at least two years. And third, the wage
insurance would not be paid until the workers found new jopbs, which would
provide a strong incentive to look for work quickly and increase the chances
that they would get on-the-job retraining. On-the-job training is always
the best way to learn new skills —instead of having to sign up for
some general government training program, with no promise of a job at the other
end, and go through that while remaining unemployed.
(pp. 293-295)
If you want to know why two decades of macroeconomic reform wholesale at the
top have not slowed the spread of poverty and produced enough new jobs in key
countries of Latin America, Africa, the Arab world, and the former Soviet
Empire, it is because there has been too little reform retail. According to
the IFC report [the Doing Business in 2004 report, published by the
World Bank's
International Finance Corporation], if you want to create productive jobs
(the kind that lead to rising standards of living), and if you want to
stimulate the growth of new businesses (the kind that innovate, compete, and
create wealth), you need a regulatory environment that makes it easy to start
a business, easy to adjust a business to changing market circumstances and
opportunities, and easy to close a business that goes bankrupt, so that the
capital can be freed up for more productive uses.
(pp. 319-320)
I once heard Jerry Yang, the cofounder of Yahoo!, quote a senior Chinese government official as saying: "Where people
have hope, you have a middle class". I think this is a very useful insight.
The existence of large, stable middle classes around the world is crucial to
geopolitical stability, but middle class is a state of mind, not a state of
income. That's why a majority of Americans always describe themselves
as "middle class", even though by income statistics some of them wouldn't
be considered as such. "Middle class" is another way of describing people
who believe that they have a pathway out of poverty or lower-income status
toward a higher standard of living and a better future for their kids.
You can be in the middle class in your head whether you make $2 a day or
$200, if you believe in social mobility —that your kids have a chance
to live better than you do— and that hard work and playing by the rules
of your society will get you where you want to go.
(pp. 375-376)
Let's pause for a minute here and trace how the antiglobalization movement lost touch with the
true aspirations of the world's poor. The antiglobalization movement emerged
at the World
Trade Organization conference in Seattle in 1999 and then
spread around the world in subsequent years, usually gathering to attack
meetings of the World
Bank, the IMF, and the G-8
industrialized nations. From its origins, the movement that emerged in
Seattle was a primarily Western-driven phenomenon, which was why you saw so
few people of color in the crowds. It was driven by five disparate forces.
One was upper-middle-class American liberal guilt at the incredible wealth
and power that America had amassed in the wake of the fall of the Berlin Wall and the dot-com boom. At the peak of the stock
market boom, lots of pampered American college kids, wearing their branded
clothing, began to get interested in sweatshops as a way of expiating their guilt. The second force
driving it was a rear-guard push by the Old Left —socialists, anarchists,
and Trotskyites—
in alliance with protectionist trade unions. Their strategy was to piggyback on rising concerns about
globalization to bring back some form of socialism, even though these ideas
had been rejected as bankrupt by the very people in the former Soviet Empire and China who had lived under them longest. (Now you
know why there was no antiglobalization movement to speak of in Russia,
China, or Eastern Europe). These Old Left forces wanted to spark a debate
about whether we globalize. They claimed to speak in the name of the
Third World poor, but
the bankrupt economic policies they advocated made them, in my view, the
Coalition to Keep Poor People Poor. The third force was a more amorphous
group. It was made up of many people who gave passive support to the
antiglobalization movement from many countries, because they saw in it some
kind of protest against the speed at which the old world was disappearing and
becoming flat.
The fourth force driving the movement, which was particularly strong in
Europe and in the Islamic
world, was anti-Americanism. The disparity between American economic and political power and
everybody else's had grown so wide after the fall of the Soviet Empire that
America began to —or was perceived to— touch people's lives
around the planet, directly or indirectly, more than their own governments
did. As people around the world began to intuit this, a movement emerged,
which Seattle both reflected and helped to catalyze, whereby people said, in
effect, "If America is not touching my life directly or indirectly more than
my own government, then I want to have a vote in America's power". At the
time of Seattle, the "touching" that people were most concerned with was from
American economic and cultural power, and therefore the demand for a vote
tended to focus around economic rule-making institutions like the World Trade Organization.
America in the 1990s, under President Clinton, was perceived as a big dumb dragon, pushing people
around in the economic and cultural speheres, knowingly and unknowingly. We
were Puff the Magic Dragon, and people wanted a vote in what we were puffing.
Then came 9/11. And America
transformed itself from Puff the Magic Dragon, touching people around the
world economically and culturally, into Godzilla with an arrow in his shoulder,
spitting fire and tossing around his tail wildly, touching people's lives in
military and security terms, not just economic and cultural ones. As that
happened, people in the world began to say, "Now we really want a vote
in how America wields its power" —and in many ways the whole Iraq war debate was a surrogate debate
about that.
(pp. 384-386)
There is a huge political vacuum now waiting to be filled. There is a
real role today for a movement that could advance the agenda of how we
globalize —not whether we globalize. The best place such a
movement could start is rural India.
(p. 387)
So although this may sound odd coming from me, it is totally consistent with
this whole book: What the world doesn't need now is for the
antiglobalization movement to go away. We just need it to grow up. This
movement had a lot of energy and a lot of mobilizing capacity. What it lacked
was a coherent agenda for assisting the poor by collaborating with them in a
way that could actually help them. The activist groups that are helping
alleviate poverty the most are those working at the local village level in
places like rural India, Africa and China to spotlight and fight corruption
and to promote accountability, transparency, education, and property rights.
You don't help the world's poor by dressing up in a turtle outfit and throwing
a stone through McDonald's window. You help them by getting them the tools
and institutions to help themselves. It may not be as sexy as protesting
against world leaders in the streets of Washington and Genoa, and getting lots
of attention on CNN, but it is a lot more
important. Just ask any Indian villager.
(p. 389)
When Muslim radicals
and fundamentalists
look at the West, they see only the openness that makes us, in their eyes,
decadent and promiscuous. They see only the openness that has produced
Britney Spears and
Janet Jackson. They
do not see, and do not want to see, the openess —the freedom of thought
and inquiry— that has made us powerful, the openness that has produced
Bill Gates and
Sally Ride. They
deliberately define it all as decadence. Because if openness, women's
empowerment, and freedom of thought and inquiry are the real sources of the
West's economic strength, then the Arab-Muslim world would have to change.
And the fundamentalists and extremists do not want to change.
(...)
Islamo-Leninism, in many ways, emerged from the same historical context as
the radical European ideologies of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.
Fascism and Marxist-Leninism grew out of the
rapid industrialization and modernization of Germany and Central Europe, where communities living in tightly bonded
villages and extended families suddenly got shattered and the sons and fathers
went off to the urban areas to work for big industrial companies. In this age
of transitions, young men in particular lost a sense of identity, rootedness,
and personal dignity that had been provided by traditional social
structures. In that vacuum, along came Hitler, Lenin,
and Mussolini, who told
these young men that they had an answer for their feelings of dislocation and
humiliation: You may not be in the village or small town anymore, but you are
still proud, dignified members of a larger community —the working class,
or the Aryan nation.
(pp. 393-395)
Unfortunately, bin Laden and his colleagues haev found it all too easy to enlist recruits in the
Arab-Muslim world. I think this has to do, in part, with the state of
half-flatness that many Arab-Muslim young people are living in, particularly
those in Europe. They have been raised to believe that Islam is the most perfect and complete expression of
God's monotheistic
message and that the Prophet
Muhammed is God's last and most perfect messenger. This is not a
criticism. This is Islam's self-identity. Yet, in a flat world, these youth,
particularly those living in Europe, can and do look around and see that the
Arab-Muslim world, in too many cases, has fallen behind the rest of the
planet. How can that be? these young Arabs and Muslims must ask
themselves. If we have the superior faith, and if our faith is all
encompassing of religion, politics, and economics, why are others living so
much better?
(p. 397)
I interviewed the Japanese manager of a major US multinational that was
headquartered in Dalian, in northeastern China. "China is following the
path of Japan and Korea", said the executive, on the condition that he and
his company not be quoted by name, "and the big question is, Can the world
afford to have 1.3 billion people following that path and driving the same
cars and using the same amount of energy? So I see the flattening of the
world, but the challenge of the twenty-first century is, Are we going to
hit another oil crisis? The oil crisis in the 1970s coincided with Japan and Europe rising. [There
was a time] when the US was the only big consumer of oil, but when Japan and
Europe came in, OPEC got the
power. But when China and India come into being the consumers, it will be a
huge challenge that is an order of magnitude different. It is megapolitics.
The limits of growth in the 1970s were overcome with technology. We got
smarter than before, equipment became more efficient, and energy consumption
per head was lower. But now [with China, India, and Russia all coming on
strong] it is multiplied by a factor of ten. There is something we really
need to be serious about. We cannot restrict China, [Russia,] and India.
They will grow and they must grow".
(pp. 410-411)
The Golden Arches Theory of Conflict Prevention has been substituted
with the Dell Theory of Conflict Prevention.
The feeling of personal insecurity and nuclear terrorism.
Entertainment factor: 7/10
Intellectual factor: 5/10
|